hn-classics/_stories/1995/12330387.md

7.0 KiB

created_at title url author points story_text comment_text num_comments story_id story_title story_url parent_id created_at_i _tags objectID year
2016-08-21T11:00:54.000Z Animals “lie” to their own kind to get what they want (1995) http://www.rochester.edu/news/show.php?id=1421 ForFreedom 42 12 1471777254
story
author_ForFreedom
story_12330387
12330387 1995

Source

Do Animals "Lie"? Yes, Even to Their Own Kind, Biologist Says

: Rochester News

Search

University of Rochester

Do Animals "Lie"? Yes, Even to Their Own Kind, Biologist Says

September 25, 1995

Email Print Story

When in a tight spot, animals "lie" to their own kind to get what they want, a University of Rochester biologist has found. In work described in the current issue of the Journal of Theoretical Biology, Eldridge Adams shows that within a single species, it is possible for some members to deceive others.

By proving that the weaker are able to deceive the stronger to survive, Adams' findings runs counter to a common belief by biologists that communication within a species must always be reliable and honest.

"We've shown that the communication is not always reliable, and that in theory, you shouldn't expect it to be," says Adams, who began the work as a graduate student at the University of California at Berkeley.

Biologists have long recognized that deception is commonplace in communication between different species. But most believed bluffing among animals of a single species should be rare or impossible.

To demonstrate how widespread deception between members of the same species could be, Adams watched hundreds of confrontations between two-inch, crayfish-like stomatopod crustaceans, whose bluffing was originally observed by behavioral ecologists Roy Caldwell and Rick Steger. Working with co-author Michael Mesterton-Gibbons of Florida State University, Adams modeled a confrontation mathematically and proves in a game theory model that bluffing is possible in a stable communication system.

Adams studied one species of stomatopod crustacean, Gonodactylus bredini, in Panama while doing graduate work under Caldwell. The creatures, known to sushi connoisseurs as mantis shrimp, live in cavities in shallow, tropical waters.

Stomatopods typically compete over these cavities, and when a confrontation looms, they can either flee or fight. If the creature chooses to fight, it often invokes a threat display, holding its appendages out to the side and lifting its head aggressively. If the opponent chooses to fight, the creatures use their appendages to whack each other with considerable force. (Stomatopods are good at this: They regularly beat senseless crabs and other hard sea creatures before cracking the shells open and gulping them down; their striking force is so great that marine biologists have nicknamed them "thumb busters.")

If threats were always honest, or reliable, only the strongest creatures -- those able to back up a threat with deadly force -- would menace others. But both the strongest and the weakest stomatopods threaten. In fact, creatures rely on threats most when they are weakest: immediately after molting, when their new skeleton is still hardening up and they don't even have hard appendages capable of crushing an opponent. "These threats often drive off opponents," says Adams, "yet they're certainly not reliable. These animals are bluffing, and they would be readily killed in a fight."

Biologists have long thought that such widespread bluffing wasn't possible in a stable communication system. If weak animals use threats deceptively, they reasoned, threats would become so common that the communication system would quickly break down because other animals wouldn't pay attention to any threats, whether real or deceptive. Adams and Mesterton-Gibbons have shown that a system can remain stable even though some members bluff successfully.

Adams likens the phenomenon to a game of draw poker between two people. "Each person knows his or her own strength, but not the strength of the opponent. Sometimes the optimal strategy is to threaten the opponent by raising the stakes, even though you have a weak hand."

This work was funded by the Smithsonian Institution and the Packard Foundation. tr

Contact: Tom Rickey, (585) 275-7954, or Eldridge Adams, (585) 275-3007


Back to the Newsroom

About the University of Rochester
The University of Rochester (www.rochester.edu) is one of the nation's leading private universities. Located in Rochester, N.Y., the University gives students exceptional opportunities for interdisciplinary study and close collaboration with faculty through its unique cluster-based curriculum. Its College, School of Arts and Sciences, and Hajim School of Engineering and Applied Sciences are complemented by its Eastman School of Music, Simon School of Business, Warner School of Education, Laboratory for Laser Energetics, School of Medicine and Dentistry, School of Nursing, Eastman Institute for Oral Health, and the Memorial Art Gallery.

PR 1421, MS 0

Facebook

The Meliora Challenge

EMERGENCY INFO
© University of Rochester 1996-2013